Legal Framework for Housing Finance

 

Legal Framework for Housing Finance

This page focuses on legal and regulatory issues in housing finance. Housing finance may be subject to a wide range of legal and regulatory enactments governing every stage of the lending process, including, for example, the form and content of loan information disclosed to borrowers, the rules for creating a mortgage, and the procedures for enforcing a creditor’s security rights. Approaches to legal regulation of housing finance may differ significantly among countries. This page will address current legal issues in housing lending as well as best practice ideas for legal and regulatory development.

The topics covered on this page may include legal and regulatory developments affecting loan origination and mortgage creation, consumer protection, and enforcement of creditors’ rights. This page may also note key developments in some areas of law that are closely related to housing lending and necessary for development of a sound housing finance market, such as regulation of financial institutions, mortgage securities, and market participants, and are covered in more detail on other topic pages of this site.

Current laws and regulations of interest will be noted mostly on the individual country pages, but new laws and regulatory acts of particular significance may be noted here as we become aware of them, along with proposed or ongoing legal reform initiatives in various countries. The emphasis will be on issues in emerging mortgage markets, but developments in and materials from developed markets will be covered for the lessons and models they may provide.

As with other theme pages on this site, and because of the rapidly developing legal environment in many countries today, this page would benefit from advice and materials from readers in all of the countries Hofinet seeks to serve; all are encouraged to send updates on their legal regimes along with laws, regulations and policies newly adopted or under consideration.

Legal and Regulatory Issues in Housing Finance

Most housing loans are secured by mortgage of the home constructed, acquired or improved with the proceeds of the loan. While there are other forms of housing lending–housing microfinance, for example, which appears to be developing rapidly today–and other forms of loan security, these appear to comprise a relatively minor part of the total volume of housing lending. Indeed, most banking regulators insist on high-quality collateral for housing loans, even more so today as the effects of the 2007 mortgage market crisis in developed economies continue to be felt.[1] Accordingly, the essential laws of housing finance are concerned with the creation and enforcement of mortgage liens, and the depth and breadth of housing finance markets in countries may be related to the nature and quality of their laws for establishing and enforcing creditors’ rights under mortgages.

Theory of Mortgage Collateral

Laws and regulations can be either incentives or disincentives to lending and borrowing. The theory of collateral is that by providing an efficient means of recapturing an investment, the costs and risks of housing lending are reduced. In particular, shorter time periods and greater certainty in realization of collateral eliminates risks such as lost interest and loss of principal from deterioration in collateral value due to, for example, unpaid taxes or lack of property maintenance. Simplification of enforcement procedures also may tend to reduce transaction costs. Reduction of transaction costs and financial risks means greater proceeds from sale of collateral, which benefits not only the creditor, but in theory the debtor also. Reduced costs and greater certainty in enforcement are believed to result in lower risk premiums in interest rates, and greater willingness of creditors to make more credit available for housing construction and acquisition, either going deeper into the socio-economic strata or offering larger loans.

Some Empirical Evidence

Arriving at compelling conclusions regarding the relationship between the efficiency of enforcing creditors’ rights and the availability and cost of credit has not been easy. Finding data that permit cross-country comparisons, defining the appropriate indicators, and controlling for the host of external variables that affect credit markets and interest rates are only a few of the problems. Nevertheless, there is a body of empirical evidence that the theory is correct, and that an efficient system of creditors’ rights increases societal welfare.[2] Modern studies have suggested a strong relationship between the quality of laws, the efficiency of law enforcement concerning creditors’ and contract rights and the availability and cost of credit to businesses and households. Moreover, while much of this research initially focused on the laws themselves, it has become clear that the quality of the laws and quality of enforcement can be independent variables and that good laws will have more effect when they are efficiently enforced. A few examples of these findings include:

·In a 2004 study of loans to legal entities in 48 countries ranked on the basis of the strength of creditors’ legal rights, Bae and Goyal found that banks lend more, over longer terms, and charge lower rates on loans to borrowers in countries where creditors’ rights are well protected and efficiently enforced.[3] The study suggests that although strong creditors’ rights in the laws decreased interest rates, more efficient enforcement of contracts in the courts not only decreased interest rates but increased loan size and lengthened loan maturities as well.

·In a 1990 study of mortgage loan enforcement in the United States, Clauretie and Herzog found that the characteristics of the mortgage law had an effect on the losses incurred by mortgage creditors. Creditors’ losses were lower in states that allowed non-judicial enforcement of a mortgage and personal judgments against borrowers for the amounts not repaid from sale of the mortgaged property, and higher in states that established long periods for debtors to redeem the property after foreclosure sale.[4] Similar studies in the U.S. market have found that long redemption periods result in higher average interest rates on all mortgage loans in the jurisdiction in which the long periods apply.

·In a 2005 study using a sample of loans in 43 countries, Qian and Strahan estimated how various bank loan terms–including interest rates and maturity–may be affected by a country’s legal and institutional characteristics.[5] They concluded from their study that where creditor protections are strong, bank loans tend to have longer maturities and lower interest rates. ·In a 2008 study that focused on legal development in 12 Eastern European countries in transition from socialism, Haselmann, Pistor and Vig showed that the strength of laws on collateral, including the ability to efficiently pledge and register a pledge of real and personal property, significantly affected the quantity of credit available in those countries, and suggested that the increase in lending was greater for ordinary households than for business enterprises. The authors speculated that this result arises because more efficient collateral laws allow creditors to compensate for the lack of clear information regarding the credit-worthiness of individual households.[6]

·In a 1991 study, Xavier Freixas showed that in Europe the average cost as well as the duration of judicial procedures required to repossess pledged assets are inversely related to the amount of funds available to finance consumption and housing acquisitions by households.[7]

·In a 2003 study for the World Bank, Laeven and Majnoni investigated the effect of judicial efficiency on banks’ interest rate spreads for a large cross-section of 106 countries. They defined the interest rate spread as the difference between the average lending rate of the banks and the average interest rate the banks paid their depositors. They compared the interest rate spreads with standard indicators of judicial efficiency and the quality of the rule of law, including an index that takes into account the time taken to deliver judicial decisions. They found that after controlling for a number of other country characteristics, judicial efficiency, in addition to inflation, is the main determinant of interest rate spreads across countries. That is, the perceived performance of the judiciary as measured by various indicators contributes directly to the difference between the interest rate banks borrow at and the rate they lend at. Poorer performance on the judicial efficiency indicators led to higher relative interest rates. They concluded that in addition to improving the overall macroeconomic climate in a country, judicial reforms, through better enforcement of legal contracts, are critical to lowering the cost of bank credit for households and firms.[8]

·Studies indicate that even within a single country, financial outcomes vary across regions that have the same laws but different court efficiency. Bianco et al. (2005) found that in Italian provinces with longer trials or larger backlogs of pending trials, credit is less widely available than elsewhere in Italy and the interest rate spread between bank lending rates and deposit rates is greater.[9]

Relationship of Length of Trials to Amount of Credit Granted by Banks in Regions of Italy


Source: Magda Bianco & Tullio Jappelli & Marco Pagano, 2001. “Courts and Banks: Effects of Judicial Enforcement on Credit Markets,” CSEF Working Papers 58, Centre for Studies in Economics and Finance (CSEF), University of Naples, Italy, revised 09 Apr. 2002.

As a general proposition, there appears to be a consensus that poor legal fundamentals–in particular the inability to create and enforce a mortgage lien in a reasonably efficient and cost-effective manner–leads to increased risk of lending, higher risk premiums in loan interest rates, higher transactions costs and markets that are both smaller and shallower in terms of income strata served. Regardless of the statistical proofs, it seems self-evident that any rules or procedures that increase the risks and costs associated with lending will have a price, and the question is, what form does the price take, and who is paying it? The price may be in higher interest rates or less credit than would otherwise be available, or may be in encouraging the use of alternative systems of securing credit that provide fewer formal legal protections to debtors.

Lack of legal guidance

There are several ways in which inadequate legal regimes may affect the breadth and depth of housing finance markets. One has been lack of clear legal guidance for lenders in the laws of some emerging country markets. Lenders are reluctant to be pioneers in situations where the laws are unclear and there is lack of legal precedent, as is the case in many emerging markets. This concern seems to be decreasing as better mortgage laws are adopted and experience with housing finance is gained by lenders, borrowers and courts. Nevertheless, in new markets some ambiguities persist. Typical areas of ambiguity may include grounds for default and enforcement of claims, judicial discretion to suspend or refuse execution, permitted defenses to lender’s claims, legal priorities among parties, and obtaining orders of eviction and possession of mortgage property.

Delays and non-judicial process

A main problem may be long delays and high costs in realization of creditors’ rights. Delays are a function of the laws and often of enforcement of the laws by the courts, which may be reluctant to enforce claims against residential property and inclined to tolerate long delays on procedural grounds. This is true not only in emerging markets but in many developed markets as well. It is perhaps noteworthy how many countries of the EU, for example, specifically allow courts to suspend execution of a mortgage for a period of time, in their discretion, for the benefit of the borrower on grounds of social protection.

Long delays in collection have in some countries led to use of alternative devices to secure housing loans and avoid the complexities and inefficiencies of mortgages. These alternatives include lease-purchase and installment sales contracts, where the title to the property remains in the name of the lending institution; or equitable mortgages or mortgage by deed, where the borrower assigns the deed to the lender; personal guarantees; and use of back-dated personal checks, which could in earlier times expose a borrower to criminal penalties in the event of default (and which have been outlawed today in many counties). Mortgage alternatives may in many cases be more efficient for the lender and arguably have increased the volume of housing lending in some countries, but they are not necessarily good for borrowers, as they often lack the basic protections of borrowers’ rights and equities that are found in mortgage laws. Despite its obvious drawbacks, one thing that can be said of mortgage law is that it provides significant legal protection to the rights and interests of debtors that other forms of security may not.

An important approach to procedural delay has been to remove mortgage enforcement from the courts through non-judicial enforcement procedures such as lender power of sale or fiduciary trust arrangements. In the former the lender itself can proceed to sell a property without going to court, subject to statutory rules, and in the latter an independent trustee or fiduciary such as a notary or bailiff can take action on behalf of the lender without court action. Understandably, non-judicial enforcement of mortgages is a matter of some controversy in many countries, and even in the United States a large number of states will not allow it. In some places there may be a sense that banks are predatory and will institute unjustified enforcement actions to profit from resale of the property, though there has been little evidence of that, and much more evidence that taking and selling property is the last resort for most lenders and in fact often results in significant losses. (The recent mortgage market crisis in the United States may throw a different light on this issue by suggesting that actual predatory behavior of lending institutions is irrelevant if the lenders are negligent and even recklessly indifferent with respect to their loan underwriting practices.)

Similarly, the laws of most countries today require some sort of public auction sale of mortgaged property, based on the expectation that public sales are more transparent and in theory should result in market prices for auctioned property. In fact the evidence to support those propositions is also lacking and good arguments can be made that private sale through normal market mechanism may provide benefits to both lenders and borrowers.

Foreclosure Times Around the World

Source: Safavian, Mehnaz, Kravkova, Mariya, & Butler, Stephen,, Mortgage Registration and Foreclosure Around the Globe: Evidence from 42 Nations, 24 Housing Finance International 4, June 2009.

Balancing interests

There have been and are ongoing in many countries today efforts to reach a reasonable comprise between the rights and interests of both borrowers and lenders, which is what mortgage law should be about. Countries have been trying through amendments to laws and other measures to make enforcement more efficient, while at the same time protecting the essential rights of borrowers, including by adopting well-regulated non-judicial procedures, providing for accelerated enforcement procedures, reducing frivolous appeals, and allowing provisional execution pending completion of appeal. On the other side, following the mortgage market crisis in developed countries in which mortgage law has been settled for many years, more attention is being paid to the needs and rights of borrowers and more constraints are being considered on loan underwriting and disclosure practices, for example. These developments are likely to continue for some time, and they will be reflected in the content of this site.


[1] See generally on this site Thematic Review on Mortgage Underwriting and Origination Practices, Peer Review Report, Financial Stability Board, 17 March 2011; Review of the Differentiated Nature and Scope of Financial Regulation: Key Issues and Recommendations, Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, The Joint Forum, January 2010; Interagency Guidelines for Real Estate Lending Policies, Appendix 5 to Chapter 24, Part 365 of the US Code of Federal Regulations (CFR). The importance for banking supervision of high-quality real estate collateral is implied in the centrality of the concepts of loan to value ratio (LTV) and accurate, independent property valuations to much of the current critique of the banking practice and banking supervision leading up to the recent financial crisis. [2] See, for example, K. M. Pence, Foreclosing on Opportunity: State Law and Mortgage Credit, 88 Review of Economics and Statistics 1, pp. 177-182 (2006); Japelli, M. Pagano & M. Bianco, “Courts and Banks: Effects of Judicial Enforcement on Credit Markets,” Working Paper No. 58, Center for Studies in Economics and Finance, University of Salerno, April, 2002; A. Padilla & A. Requejo, “The Costs and Benefits of Enforcing Creditors Rights: Theory and Evidence,” in Marco Pagano (ed.), Defusing Default: Incentives and Institutions, (Washington, DC, Johns Hopkins University Press, 2001); La Porta, R, F. Lopez de Silanes, A. Shleifer and R.W. Vishny, “Law and Finance,” 106 Journal of Political Economy, pp. 1113-55 (1998); La Porta, R, F. Lopez de Silanes, A. Shleifer and R.W. Vishny, “Legal Determinants of External Finance,” 52 Journal of Finance, pp. 1131-1150 (1997); L. D. Jones, Deficiency Judgments and the Exercise of the Default Option in Home Mortgage Loans, 36 Journal of Law and Economics 1, pp. 115-138 (1993); An Economic Analysis of Mortgagor Protection Laws, 77 Virginia Law Review 3, pp. 489-538 (Apr. 1991); B. Balkenhol & H. Schutte, “Collateral, Collateral Law and Collateral Substitutes,” Working Paper No. 26, International Labor Office, Geneva; Mark Meador, “The Effect of Mortgage Laws On Home Mortgage Rates,” 34 Journal of Economics and Business 2, pp. 143-148, 1982. [3] Kee-Hong Bae and Vidhan K. Goyal, Creditor Rights, Enforcement, and Bank Loans: Property Rights Protection and Bank Loan Pricing, Working Paper, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, 2004. [4] Terrence M. Clauretie & Thomas Herzog, The Effect of State Foreclosure Laws on Loan Losses: Evidence from the Mortgage Insurance Industry, 22 Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 2, pp. 221-233, May 1990. [5]How Laws and Institutions Shape Financial Contracts: The Case of Bank Loans,” 62 Journal of Finance 6, pp. 2803-2834, December 2005. [6] Rainer Haselmann, Katharina Pistor and Vikrant Vig, How Law Affects Lending, Columbia Law and Economics Working Paper 285, August 2008. [7] Freixas, X. El mercado hipotecario español: Situación actual y proyecto de reforma, Madrid, Spain: Fundación de Estudios de Economía Aplicada, 1991. [8] Luc Laeven and Giovanni Majnoni, Does Judicial Efficiency Lower the Cost of Credit? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3159, October 2003. [9] Magda Bianco, Tullio Jappelli & Marco Pagano, 2001. “Courts and Banks: Effects of Judicial Enforcement on Credit Markets,” CSEF Working Papers 58, Centre for Studies in Economics and Finance (CSEF), University of Naples, Italy, April 2002.

 

Related Documents
  Publish Date Title Author
2017Evidence and Innovation in Housing Law and PolicyLee Anne Fennell and Benjamin J. Keys
2014IMF Selected Issues Report
20142014 Financial Stability Report
2013Land and Buildings Taxes Act
2013Property Taxes in Selected Asian CountriesMinistry of Finance of the Republic of Indonesia Directorate General of Fiscal Balance
2013Chile: subsidies, credit and housing deficitFernando Garcia de Freitas
May 2012Danish Covered Bond HandbookDanske Markets
January 2012A Guide to Global Covered Bond LegislationAnne Caris, Caspar Cook, Alexander Batchvarov
2012 FSB Principles for Sound Residential Mortgage Underwriting PracticesFinancial Stability Board (FSB)
2012America’s Mortgage Laws in Historical PerspectiveAndra Ghent
2012The Interaction of Monetary and Macroprudential PoliciesHeedon Kang
2011Law 189-11 Mortgage Legal CodeNational Congress of the Dominican Republic
2011Cyprus Mortgage Legal InformationDoros Theodorou
2011The Missing Foundations of Housing Finance: Incomplete Markets, Fragmented Policies and Emerging Solutions in GuatemalaMario Cuevas, Sigfrido Lée and María Isabel Bonilla
2011Regulation Z: Truth in Lending (Ability to Pay)Jennifer J. Johnson
2011Retail Product Development and Governance – Structured Products ReviewFSA
2011Thematic Review on Mortgage Underwriting and Origination PracticesFinancial Stability Board (FSB)
2011A Resource Guide to Housing in South Africa 1994-2010Kate Tissington
2011Housing and Real Estate Finance in the Middle East And North Africa CountriesOliver Hassler
2011Uganda Guidelines for Micro-credit Bank of Uganda
2010Setting the Framework: Connecting Public and Private SectorMarja Hoek-Smit
2010Regulation of Foreign Currency Mortgage Loans: The Case of Transition Countries in Central and Eastern Europe Hans-Joachim (Achim) Dübel and Simon Walley
2010SAFE Act: Final RuleJohn C. Dugan
2010Report to Congress on the Root Causes of the Foreclosure CrisisChristopher E. Herbert
2009HOUSING SUPPLY IN ALGERIA: AFFORDABILITY MATTERS RATHER THAN AVAILABILITYTahar Bellal
2007Mortgages in Transition Economies: The Legal Framework for Mortgages and Mortgage SecuritiesEuropean Bank for Reconstruction and Development
2007Housing Finance Gap Analysis in  Francophone Sub-Saharan AfricaCanada Mortgage Housing Corporation
2005Housing Finance: New and Old Models in Central Europe, Russia, and KazakhstanEdited by József Hegedüs and Raymond J. Struyk
2004Creditor Rights, Enforcement, and Bank LoansKee-Hong Bae and Vidhan K. Goyal
2003Does Judicial Efficiency Lower the Cost of Credit?Luc Laeven and Giovanni Majnoni
2002Courts and Banks: Effects of Judicial Enforcement on Credit MarketsTullio Jappelli, Marco Pagano, Magda Bianco
December 1999 Mortgage Market Reform in EgyptNathan Associates Inc.
1997Legal Determinants of External FinanceFlorencio López de Silanes
A Decade of Regulation in Paraguay (Spanish)Jorge Luis Schreiner Marengo

About the Editor

Stephen Brian Butler
Contact
Website

Stephen B. Butler is a Principal Research Scientist in the International Projects Department of NORC at the University of Chicago.He has advised international donor agencies and ministries, central banks and regulatory commissions in 30 transitional and developing countries in 5 regions, focusing on land reform and administration, housing and housing finance, and mortgage market development.